The secondary and tertiary benefits are likely to be of even greater value. Some can be measured readily but many are difficult to qualify. A new facility is likely to lure suppliers and their employees to the area. Spouses bring their own businesses and skillsets to the host community, where they are absorbed by the market as start-ups or sustainable additions to existing employers. The correlation between a vibrantly diverse economy and lower rates of violent crime and chronic disease is so high that mutual causation is indisputable. It may be hard to quantify these benefits, but they sure are valuable. Communities, and states to a lesser extent, will frequently pay for them through economic incentives. The advocate's skill in reducing those benefits to economic value and identifying their intangible value for decision makers can make or break an incentives package and where the recruited company locates its project. The importance of the real estate to the success of a project frequently transcends its economic value. Location has, of course, great symbolic value. Companies accept certain costs to be located where economic benefits can be derived, especially where the location itself communicates the mission, the ethos and future of the company. If a community already has the desired cachet, then it will probably have to pay less to land the project. Communities lacking it will have to pay more for the project and the cachet that they covet. This factor is akin to good will on a balance sheet. Much like good will, it can be easily overstated, resulting in a company overspending on its real estate or in a community overpaying for a project. This is, however, just the top line of how real estate and the application of local law regarding real estate and economic development can affect a project. The availability of the real estate necessary for the project may be critical to where the project goes and how it is valued. Its readiness may help to satisfy demand for the most valuable resource of all, time (I admit that I took that from Wall Street: Money Never Sleeps, but that does not diminish its accuracy). A community that owns its best sites for economic development has a competitive advantage. In fact, this advantage has become so valued that site in a project may be necessary to qualify for consideration. A lawyer's ability to help the parties obtain site control and assess its security will probably become critical at some point in the process. A lawyer's ability to apply the subset of real estate laws which apply to acquisition and disposition by public agencies for purposes of economic development can directly impact the bottom lines on the spreadsheet and on the schedule. For example, public agencies may have greater flexibility in how they buy, sell or otherwise convey real property when it is for economic development, but that flexibility frequently calls for greater disclosure to the public and an economic justification on the part of public decision-makers. For example, the local government may be able to contract with whomever it wishes for a discretionary price instead of having to convey the property for market value as determined by public bidding. However, the local government may be obligated to disclose the market value of the property and to find specifically that its conveyance will result in the creation of jobs paying more than the local average. In these cases real estate is a field of opportunity fraught with potential pitfalls. An economic development lawyer's ability to envision and then to plot a course through that field, and that lawyer's ability to communicate the merits and the risks of that course, may determine the nature of the relationship between the company representing an opportunity and the communities which want to make that opportunity their own. A close friend recently asked me why someone would hire me to work on an economic development project with a real estate component. I told her that I can make these things happen without bringing out the opposition, or at least without enraging it. If it satisfied her, then it will probably satisfy most clients. It does not always work out according to plan. This could mean fewer hires than projected, a lower capital investment than promised, the relocation of the company or the failure of the business. None of this is good, but an effective economic development lawyer can mitigate the damage proactively and, to a lesser extent, reactively. This may up fees, or later by the transfer of property, the renegotiation of economic development agreements or the dreaded refinancing of incentives. The best defensive course will probably depend on what the law allows, the terms of the initial agreements, and the negotiating positions that the parties hold, like most other contracts "in turnaround." Structuring the deals so that recoupment of the public investment is not the only remedy is savvy and artful, because it is frequently something easy to provide for but hard to enforce. Finding an alternative means such as payments-in-kind of real property or devising the incentives so that they are paid out as public benefits are derived is generally a wiser course. These projects generally involve the passage of time, relatively high reward and some level of risk, so an effective lawyer will help to manage the downside for clients proactively with those factors in mind. Skillfully applied knowledge of the laws and contractual terms regarding these unfortunate events can result in effectively managing them as well as the expectations and relationships which hinge upon them. If you are good, then you will get to do it again. The importance of economic incentives to a company's decision on where to land varies significantly based on the industry, the kind of workforce it requires, the portability of the project and the value of the incentives that a community, or a competing community, is willing to provide in exchange for the project. Incentives may serve as the "ante" one pays at the start of the selection process, or they may be what puts one location over the top after the field is narrowed. The high likelihood that incentives, the laws of economic development and the skill with which those laws are applied will come into play at one stage or another mean that companies and agencies should keep those factors and their economic development lawyers in mind throughout the process. Their importance will require at least one lawyer who can analyze the value of the project in relation to the law and communicate that particular value to decision makers including the general public, elected officials and C-level executives in the public and private sectors. |